Skip to main content
About HEC About HEC
Summer School Summer School
Faculty & Research Faculty & Research
Master’s programs Master’s programs
Bachelor Programs Bachelor Programs
MBA Programs MBA Programs
PhD Program PhD Program
Executive Education Executive Education
HEC Online HEC Online
About HEC
Overview Overview
Who
We Are
Who
We Are
Égalité des chances Égalité des chances
HEC Talents HEC Talents
International International
Sustainability Sustainability
Diversity
& Inclusion
Diversity
& Inclusion
The HEC
Foundation
The HEC
Foundation
Campus life Campus life
Activity Reports Activity Reports
Summer School
Youth Programs Youth Programs
Summer programs Summer programs
Online Programs Online Programs
Faculty & Research
Overview Overview
Faculty Directory Faculty Directory
Departments Departments
Centers Centers
Chairs Chairs
Grants Grants
Knowledge@HEC Knowledge@HEC
Master’s programs
Master in
Management
Master in
Management
Master's
Programs
Master's
Programs
Double Degree
Programs
Double Degree
Programs
Bachelor
Programs
Bachelor
Programs
Summer
Programs
Summer
Programs
Exchange
students
Exchange
students
Student
Life
Student
Life
Our
Difference
Our
Difference
Bachelor Programs
Overview Overview
Course content Course content
Admissions Admissions
Fees and Financing Fees and Financing
MBA Programs
MBA MBA
Executive MBA Executive MBA
TRIUM EMBA TRIUM EMBA
PhD Program
Overview Overview
HEC Difference HEC Difference
Program details Program details
Research areas Research areas
HEC Community HEC Community
Placement Placement
Job Market Job Market
Admissions Admissions
Financing Financing
FAQ FAQ
Executive Education
Home Home
About us About us
Management topics Management topics
Open Programs Open Programs
Custom Programs Custom Programs
Events/News Events/News
Contacts Contacts
HEC Online
Overview Overview
Executive programs Executive programs
MOOCs MOOCs
Summer Programs Summer Programs
Youth programs Youth programs
Article

Earnings from Entrepreneurship: Less than Salaried Employment or Just Less Measurable?

Entrepreneurship and Startups
Published on:

With the exception of a few high-flying lawyers and other such “superstar” entrepreneurs, individuals who switch to self-employment tend to earn less on average than they do as wage-earning employees. They also work longer hours and no longer receive paid leave. Is there a rational explanation as to why so many choose the entrepreneurial path in spite of these disadvantages? Could the lower earnings associated with entrepreneurship be a function of income underreporting?

Earnings from entrepreneurship

Cubicle-dwellers dreaming of becoming self-employed might want to consider the following sobering facts before quitting their day jobs. On average, entrepreneurs earn 4% to 15% less per year than their wage-earner counterparts, work longer hours, experience higher income risk, and their earnings rise less quickly over time. Only a small fraction of entrepreneurs end up making a lot more money than they did as employees . In other words, for every Richard Branson, there are thousands of restaurant owners, graphic designers, and plumbers slaving away for less than what they would as salaried employees. If a difference in earnings of 4% to 15% per year doesn’t sound like much, as Thomas Astebro points out, “Over a lifetime, it adds up to a substantial amount in terms of foregone earnings.”

Academics were the only segment of the population for which the researcher did not find a significant income discrepancy between salaried employees and independents. He suggests the main reason is the “academic discount,” or downward pressure on university salaries, related to the strong demand for academic positions regardless of pay level. Other than that exceptional case, the puzzle remains: why would any rational individual choose to become an entrepreneur instead of a salaried employee if it were both riskier and less rewarding in financial terms?

Explaining the entrepreneurial choice

As Thomas Astebro and his co-author Jing Chen write in their recent article on the subject, there are many theories competing to solve the riddle of the entrepreneurial choice. “Matching and learning” models, and others based on labor market frictions, look at the entry and exit mechanisms of the entrepreneurial and wage markets. “For example, those with lower abilities get squeezed out of the labor market, and when fired go into entrepreneurship,” says Thomas Astebro. In that case, lower skills would thus explain lower wages. Also, those who have already invested considerable amounts into entrepreneurship may persist even with lower realization in misguided attempts to recover sunk costs. Another potential explanation for the preference for entrepreneurship might simply be the non-financial rewards offered by independent work, such as autonomy, flexibility, and better use of personal skills. Who can argue against pursuing a passion for photography or stand-up comedy, even if it comes at a cost? But is there truly a cost, or might the earnings gap simply be a function of income underreporting?

 

 In surveys, one out of three declines to answer questions about income.

 

Hiding income from taxman

The most potent explanation that Thomas Astebro and his co-author found was income underreporting by entrepreneurs. Indeed, entrepreneurs have many opportunities to work without invoicing, while, in contrast, notes the researcher, “for a wage-earner, it’s nearly impossible.” He points out that tax evasion is a strong motivation to underreport income. It is an established fact that 99.5% of wages and salaries were voluntarily reported to US tax authorities in 1987 versus only 51% of known entrepreneurial earnings. Thomas Astebro believes the incentive to underreport is present even when measuring income for research purposes through surveys rather than by going through tax-filing data. “We speculate that entrepreneurs think we will report them to the tax office,” he says. Furthermore, money is always a sensitive subject. “In surveys you can ask people pretty much anything, are they married, do they have kids, how long do they commute, but one out of three declines to answer questions about income,” he says. If entrepreneurs do earn more than what they report, then the income discrepancy puzzle disappears.

The devil is in the details: food expenditures

To test their hypothesis, Thomas Astebro and his colleague worked from a model that uses food expenditures to indicate levels of income underreporting . Studying more than a decade of data from a major US household panel survey, they found that the self-employed spent significantly more than salaried employees on food. According to the model, the translation in terms of underreported income lifts entrepreneurial average earnings by between 10% and 40%. “If the method is sound, rather than a deficit, there is a premium to entrepreneurship in terms of income,” concludes Thomas Astebro. But he warns that the model rests on the assumption that the self-employed and salaried employees have the same food preferences, an assumption he challenges.

“Entrepreneurs may go to restaurants more often for networking purposes, for meetings, to generate business,” he points out. Indeed, when the analysis is fine-tuned to focus on food consumed at home, the difference between the two populations lessens. One Canadian study thus adjusted found that the earnings discrepancy worked out to an average of CAN $3,000 over one year, which is far less of a discrepancy. But even if the fraction of underreporting is less, and earnings from entrepreneurship are “only” 7% to 30% more, it is still significant. “We have uncovered the most potent explanation, now it’s a matter of finding the correct method,” concludes Thomas Astebro.

How did you test this theory?

Focus - Methodologie
The research team used data from the World Values Survey (WVS), a database launched in 1981 that holds the specific features, opinions and behaviors of 200,000 people from around the world aged 15 to 82. They selected 30 questions with the highest statistical coverage and compared data from 1989 to 2004 and then designed quantitative indicators for the cultural distance between two countries. They drew on the cultural transmission model of Alberto Bisin and Thierry Verdier for their theoretical basis.
Based on an interview with Thomas Astebro and the article “The entrepreneurial earnings puzzle: Mismeasurement or real?” co-written by J. Chen (Journal of Business Venturing , 2014, vol. 29, pp. 88-105).

Related content on Entrepreneurship and Startups

Entrepreneurship and Startups
Two HEC Startups Use Plants and Satellites to Drive Sustainability
Podcasts
AI Can Level Global Playing Field
Carlos Serrano
Carlos Serrano
Associate Professor
researcher in a tech startup_vignette
Entrepreneurship and Startups

Startups Founded by Ph.D.s Decline: Why One Should Worry

By Thomas Åstebro

station F HEC - vignette

HEC Paris Incubator at the Station F, Paris

Entrepreneurship and Startups

Lean Startup: Why Do So Many New Startups Follow the Same Development Philosophy?

By Sebastian Becker