Skip to main content
About HEC About HEC
Summer School Summer School
Faculty & Research Faculty & Research
Master’s programs Master’s programs
Bachelor Programs Bachelor Programs
MBA Programs MBA Programs
PhD Program PhD Program
Executive Education Executive Education
HEC Online HEC Online
About HEC
Overview Overview
Who
We Are
Who
We Are
Égalité des chances Égalité des chances
HEC Talents HEC Talents
International International
Sustainability Sustainability
Diversity
& Inclusion
Diversity
& Inclusion
The HEC
Foundation
The HEC
Foundation
Campus life Campus life
Activity Reports Activity Reports
Summer School
Youth Programs Youth Programs
Summer programs Summer programs
Online Programs Online Programs
Faculty & Research
Overview Overview
Faculty Directory Faculty Directory
Departments Departments
Centers Centers
Chairs Chairs
Grants Grants
Knowledge@HEC Knowledge@HEC
Master’s programs
Master in
Management
Master in
Management
Master's
Programs
Master's
Programs
Double Degree
Programs
Double Degree
Programs
Bachelor
Programs
Bachelor
Programs
Summer
Programs
Summer
Programs
Exchange
students
Exchange
students
Student
Life
Student
Life
Our
Difference
Our
Difference
Bachelor Programs
Overview Overview
Course content Course content
Admissions Admissions
Fees and Financing Fees and Financing
MBA Programs
MBA MBA
Executive MBA Executive MBA
TRIUM EMBA TRIUM EMBA
PhD Program
Overview Overview
HEC Difference HEC Difference
Program details Program details
Research areas Research areas
HEC Community HEC Community
Placement Placement
Job Market Job Market
Admissions Admissions
Financing Financing
FAQ FAQ
Executive Education
Home Home
About us About us
Management topics Management topics
Open Programs Open Programs
Custom Programs Custom Programs
Events/News Events/News
Contacts Contacts
HEC Online
Overview Overview
Executive programs Executive programs
MOOCs MOOCs
Summer Programs Summer Programs
Youth programs Youth programs
Article

How Investment Capital Could Induce Polluting Companies to Change for Good

How Investment Capital Could Induce Polluting Companies to Change for Good
Finance
Published on:
Updated on:

Despite environmental, social, and governance (ESG) funds gaining popularity, their impact on reducing negative externalities, such as greenhouse gas emissions, may be limited if not approached strategically. In our study, entitled “Responsible Finance: How to Optimize Impact,” forthcoming in the Review of Financial Studies, we show that investment capital could actually influence the behavior of more highly polluting companies to drive positive change for the planet.

ESG investing_cover

Every day, thousands of companies interact with employees, suppliers, and customers around the world. But their activities can indirectly affect other people, too—people who have not been consulted nor have agreed to anything—sometimes in negative ways. These so-called negative externalities of economic activity include contributing to global warming via Greenhouse gas emissions.

Negative externalities generated by corporations are a recurrent theme in policy debates. The traditional economic prescription for this problem has been regulation. One example is cap and trade schemes that allow companies to pollute a certain amount during a fixed period or sell their allowance to another firm. Another is taxing activities that generate COemissions. However, establishing processes can be cumbersome and slow, and even when in place, they often deliver variable results.

Curbing poor environmental performance via targeted financing

Investors who want to do something about reducing the negative impact of economic activity can choose to put their money into funds that use ESG criteria to determine which companies they want to invest in. 

These ESG investment funds take the environmental performance of companies into account. Companies can attain higher ESG scores by generating lower COemissions. Many high-scoring ‘green’ companies have operating procedures that enable them to slash their emissions.

If we want to see further emission cuts – a stated policy goal of the European Union – we need to consider how ESG-based investment schemes work and where they fail. At first glance, a reasonable approach for an investor concerned with environmental issues might seem to be to invest only in ecologically responsible companies with a low carbon footprint.

What are the intentions of the funds and investors?

It is important to recognize here that a presumed socially responsible investment fund is primarily concerned with raising money from its investors like any other investment fund. Such funds charge fees and make a profit. They are not, strictly speaking, in the business of lowering COemissions.

 

Whereas all investors care about the financial performance of their portfolios, some may also want to 'do the right thing' for the environment or society.

 

Individual investors also have their own concerns and motivations. Whereas all investors care about the financial performance of their portfolios, some may also want to 'do the right thing' for the environment or society. In particular, so-called value-alignment investors may be concerned with their money not being used by firms that have negative externalities. They may be less concerned with or simply unaware of the actual impact of their actions on reducing such externalities.

Can ESG investing drive down COemissions?

ESG investment funds investing only in green companies will attract value-alignment investors. These funds will continue to be invested only in green companies because that is what said investors want them to do. All parties are happy, but our research shows that their actions may have little or no impact on COemissions. 

Why? Green companies are already green, and putting more money into them will rarely make them greener. Therefore, the impact of investing in companies that, for example, are already emitting very little COis not particularly effective. Brown companies, on the other hand, will just be owned by other investors and will keep polluting as usual.

There can be exceptions to this effect. For example, one can imagine a case where the amount of money available to be invested in green sectors is larger than the total amount of money needed by those sectors, whereas the remainder of the capital in the economy is not enough to finance all brown sector companies. Thus, having invested in all the existing green companies, a sufficiently large fund would still have money left over to invest in the creation of new green companies. The green sectors will increase in size whereas fewer brown firms will be financed. Whereas this could reduce COemissions, it would have a perverse effect on financial returns. More green companies will be in competition, and their profitability will fall.

On the contrary, profitability grows for brown companies as their number falls. Thus, funds composed of green sector firms will offer poorer financial performance than those offered by more standard funds. As a consequence, only a small amount of capital would flow to ESG funds, which will not reach the critical size necessary to impact emissions. 

A less intuitive solution to boosting ESG investment impact

Surprisingly, we have shown that an alternative approach is to put money into brown companies. The key, however, is to do so with certain conditions attached, demanding that brown companies reduce their emissions to receive the funding. According to our research, this strategy is generally more effective at reducing COemissions than investing the same amount of money in companies that are already green. 

Investment capital, it turns out, is a powerful form of leverage for influencing and modifying the behavior of brown companies.

However, this approach has its own weaknesses. First, the ESG fund cannot attract capital from value-aligned investors by investing in brown companies. Second, there may be circumstances under which this approach is not feasible. For example, in a sector where available capital is abundant for investment, brown companies may find sufficient funding from investors who are not concerned about environmental performance. More responsible investors will have little or no direct leverage in such cases.

Extending leverage down the supply chain

One of our key findings involves the situation described above, where a polluting sector has plenty of cash. Here, brown companies that can easily get money without having to comply with environmental demands may nevertheless have companies among their customers operating in cash-constrained sectors. These industrial customers will need capital. Then, an ESG fund can have an impact by investing in such industrial customers, requiring them to commit to only having polluting sector suppliers’ firms who reduce their emissions. The brown companies are now compelled to go green, not because they need the investment cash, but because they will lose their customers if they do not.

 

Our research shows that conscientious investors can successfully pressure brown companies by targeting links in the supply chain that receive less investment.

 

A supply chain is made up of discreet links, each representing a company or companies in a separate sector or sub-sector. Our research shows that by targeting links in the chain that receive less investment, conscientious investors can successfully apply pressure on brown companies elsewhere in that chain from a distance.

Thus, investing in green sectors while requiring recipients of capital to select their brown suppliers among the least polluting ones might be the best way to attract value-aligned investors' capital, reduce emissions, and do this without sacrificing too much financial returns.

Takeaway: We consider the pecuniary and non-pecuniary performance of three investment strategies for socially responsible funds: exclusion, Scope 1 investing, and Scope 3 investing. 

Exclusion: Excluding polluting sectors from the fund’s portfolio has an impact only if the fund size is large enough. The impact is achieved with a low-footprint portfolio but comes at the cost of a substantial deterioration of the fund's financial performance.

Scope 1: Even a small fund can have an impact if the polluting sector is subject to capital market frictions by investing only in firms that commit to reducing their emissions. The impact comes with minimal deterioration of the fund's financial performance but is achieved with a high-footprint portfolio.  

Scope 3: By investing in clean sector firms that commit to only having polluting sector suppliers firms that reduce their emissions, even a small fund can have an impact if the clean sector is subject to capital market frictions. The impact is achieved with a low-footprint portfolio and comes with minimal deterioration of the fund's financial performance.
 

 ProsCons 
Scope 1

Even a small fund can have an impact if the polluting sector is subject to capital market frictions.

Financial performance comparable to standard funds 

High portfolio footprint makes the fund unpalatable to value-aligned investors.

Implementation requires Scope 1 monitoring.

Scope 3 strategy

Even a small fund can have an impact if the clean sector is subject to capital market frictions.


Financial performance is comparable to standard funds.
A low portfolio footprint makes the fund palatable to value-aligned investors.

Might have less impact than Scope 1.


Implementation requires Scope 3 monitoring.

Exclusion strategy

Easy to implement.


A low portfolio footprint makes the fund palatable to value-aligned investors.

Either has no impact or has an impact but generates financial performance substantially worse than that of standard funds


Both Scope 1 and Scope 3 strategies can have an impact with minimal deterioration in financial performance, but each has its pros and cons.

In summary, we propose that ESG funds should prioritize investing where competition for funding is high. By imposing restrictions on suppliers and customers, they can influence companies that are not directly financed with responsible capital.

 

Methodology

Using a general equilibrium model approach, we analyzed an ESG fund's strategy to maximize social welfare. We showed that if capital markets are subject to cash constraints, the ESG fund can raise assets and improve social welfare even though all agents are acting in their own interests. We derived the fund’s optimal policy in terms of industry allocation and pollution limits imposed on its portfolio companies.

Applications

ESG funds should prioritize investing where competition for funding is high.  By imposing restrictions on the suppliers and customers used by the firms where it invests, the fund can influence companies where negative externalities are particularly acute, whether these companies receive ESG capital or not.  
Based on an interview with HEC Paris' Finance Professor Stefano Lovo about his paper, “Socially Responsible Finance: How to Optimize Impact,” co-written with Professor Augustin Landier (HEC Paris), forthcoming in the Review of Financial Studies (already available on SSRN here).

Related content on Finance

Source: Frenta on 123RF

Finance

Reaching for the Stars: High Ratings Give Restaurants an Edge with Customers – and Lenders

By François Derrien

Sustainable Development
Reshaping Core Courses for Sustainability
Eloic Peyrache - HEC
Eloïc Peyrache
Professor, Dean
iStock-Varsovie_Vera Balacco
Finance

What Incites Companies to Invest in Green Technologies?

By Bruno Biais, Augustin Landier