Skip to main content
About HEC About HEC
Summer School Summer School
Faculty & Research Faculty & Research
Master’s programs Master’s programs
Bachelor Programs Bachelor Programs
MBA Programs MBA Programs
PhD Program PhD Program
Executive Education Executive Education
HEC Online HEC Online
About HEC
Overview Overview
Who
We Are
Who
We Are
Égalité des chances Égalité des chances
HEC Talents HEC Talents
International International
Sustainability Sustainability
Diversity
& Inclusion
Diversity
& Inclusion
The HEC
Foundation
The HEC
Foundation
Campus life Campus life
Activity Reports Activity Reports
Summer School
Youth Programs Youth Programs
Summer programs Summer programs
Online Programs Online Programs
Faculty & Research
Overview Overview
Faculty Directory Faculty Directory
Departments Departments
Centers Centers
Chairs Chairs
Grants Grants
Knowledge@HEC Knowledge@HEC
Master’s programs
Master in
Management
Master in
Management
Master's
Programs
Master's
Programs
Double Degree
Programs
Double Degree
Programs
Bachelor
Programs
Bachelor
Programs
Summer
Programs
Summer
Programs
Exchange
students
Exchange
students
Student
Life
Student
Life
Our
Difference
Our
Difference
Bachelor Programs
Overview Overview
Course content Course content
Admissions Admissions
Fees and Financing Fees and Financing
MBA Programs
MBA MBA
Executive MBA Executive MBA
TRIUM EMBA TRIUM EMBA
PhD Program
Overview Overview
HEC Difference HEC Difference
Program details Program details
Research areas Research areas
HEC Community HEC Community
Placement Placement
Job Market Job Market
Admissions Admissions
Financing Financing
FAQ FAQ
Executive Education
Home Home
About us About us
Management topics Management topics
Open Programs Open Programs
Custom Programs Custom Programs
Events/News Events/News
Contacts Contacts
HEC Online
Overview Overview
Executive programs Executive programs
MOOCs MOOCs
Summer Programs Summer Programs
Youth programs Youth programs
Article

What Incites Companies to Invest in Green Technologies?

What Incites Companies to Invest in Green Technologies?
Finance
Published on:

If companies anticipate that the government might impose caps on carbon emissions, they will likely invest in green technologies. This, in turn, drives down the cost of achieving reductions for all. That’s according to HEC Paris finance professors Augustin Landier and Bruno Biais. In “Emission Caps and Investment in Green Technologies,” the co-authors also show that if these firms don’t think carbon restrictions are coming, they won’t invest, and the government eventually will find it too costly to the economy to impose caps. In other words, companies’ expectations about future government action play a crucial role in reducing the carbon emissions driving rapid climate change. So, ask the researchers, how can a balance be found?

4 key findings: 

  1. Anticipating future regulations spurs green technology investments, lowering emission reduction costs;
  2. Early investments in green technologies create a self-fulfilling prophecy, facilitating feasible emissions caps;
  3. Private and public actions synergize for desired outcomes through a complementary equilibrium;
  4. One large investor can have a significant influence.
iStock-Varsovie_Vera Balacco_cover

Solar panels in Varsovia. Photo Credits: Vera Balacco on iStock

To mitigate global warming with catastrophic consequences, it is crucial to reduce carbon dioxide emissions significantly. But right now, governments and companies are in a bind when it comes to figuring how to accomplish that.

One reason is that while reducing one's emissions is good for all, it is individually costly: reducing emissions is a positive externality. And it’s a challenge to get companies to provide positive externalities, since it brings down their profits. They’re not necessarily going to do it without government pressure, whether it’s immediate or something that’s anticipated down the road.

You might think that the government could simply fix everything by putting hard caps on companies’ carbon output. In reality, though, government power tends to be limited by political pressures and concerns about how regulations will affect the economy.

Additionally, while government regulators have the ability to measure companies’ carbon emissions, that’s just the end result. It’s tougher for them to monitor the investments in green technologies necessary to achieve emissions reduction because it takes time for those investments to lead to innovations that cut carbon output. It’s unlikely that public-sector intervention will fully substitute for insufficient action by private companies. At the same time, it can’t be taken for granted that private sector initiatives will be enough without a degree of government involvement.

This is a serious dilemma because, as we write in our paper, there’s a real risk of insufficient investment in green technologies, which would mean that we won’t curb excessive CO2 emissions.

Is there a way for the private and public sectors to interact so that the necessary investments will be made in green technologies to reduce carbon emissions? We developed an analytical model to answer that question and found that there is indeed a way out of this quandary.

A Self-Fulfilling Prophecy

Governments are pragmatic. What they do in the long term depends upon what will be realistic at some point in the future. But what will be realistic in the future, in turn, depends upon the choices that companies make now.

Companies are also pragmatic. Anticipation is a big part of decisions on investments in technology. Waiting for the other part (the government or the company) to do the first step is sort of a chicken-and-egg situation.

Our analysis shows that when it comes to making decisions about investing in carbon-reducing innovations, companies’ expectations of what the future will be like actually help make it a reality. Here’s how that works. If companies anticipate that caps will be imposed in the future, they will invest now in green technologies so that they are prepared and ahead of the curve when that day comes. What happens, though, is that some companies’ decision to invest in green technology changes the future for everybody, even for other businesses that didn’t make the same sort of commitment. That’s because the investments have positive spillover effects, lowering the aggregate cost of technology for emission reductions.

And when green technology becomes cheaper, the government is more likely to impose emissions caps because regulators can do it without imposing that much economic hardship on companies.

Governments need companies to invest in green technologies to make regulation possible

Now consider a second scenario, in which companies expect that government, for whatever reasons, won’t impose emissions caps. As a result, the companies decide not to invest in green technology. 

That puts the government in a difficult situation, because if it imposes emissions caps and it’s too difficult and/or expensive for companies to comply, that could cause jobs to be lost and share prices to plunge on the stock market. Many economists agree that the government will have to impose tough regulations at some point. It’s just that they can’t do it too fast because it could be damaging to the economy.

 

For things to work, we need companies to invest early in green technologies and, at the same time, for the government to impose emissions caps

 

For things to work, we need companies to invest early in green technologies and, at the same time, for the government to impose emissions caps. Neither party must go it alone. Instead, the situation requires what we describe in the paper as “equilibrium complementarity,” in which the private and public sector actions have a synergistic effect.

A single investment fund could tip the balance

The study also found that a single player can have a disproportionately large influence on the outcome. A single large investment fund on the scale of BlackRock or Vanguard, or a coalition of investors committed to Environmental, Social, and Governance (ESG) values, could do it. If that big player engages with companies to foster investment in green technology, that could end up tilting the equilibrium toward emissions caps.

It’s important to mention again, though, that in the model we developed, there’s no irrationality. Often, people assume that with ESG, there’s a preference for green companies or that the market isn’t pricing climate risk correctly. Therefore, investing in green companies can make money or improve risk management and risk-averse returns. However, we’re using very standard preferences—companies that try to maximize their proceeds and investors who try to maximize profit. So basically, the baseline model is very simple and rational. We also are factoring in a political economy with a constraint, which is that 10 years from now, governments will only apply laws or regulations that are reasonable in terms of costs to the economy.

How to use the model

The model developed for this study is very generic and conceptual, and it applies to any industry where innovative technological processes for carbon reduction will need to be created through research and development, as opposed to just buying technology that’s out there and implementing it. One important takeaway from the study is that anticipation of regulation is probably the key element in deciding what is rational or not rational for a company to do. Companies need to investigate and think seriously about the plausible path for future regulation and the potential risk of going one way or another.

 

Applications

Strategic planning should incorporate the idea of “equilibrium complementarity,” in which a combination of public sector regulatory action and private action before regulation must be combined to achieve a desired outcome.   

Methodology

The researchers constructed a mathematical model to analyze the behavior of both private and public sector actors and predict the outcomes of various choices.  
Source: Based upon an interview with Augustin Landier and the working paper "Emission Caps and Investment in Green Technologies", co-authored with Bruno Biais.

Related content on Finance